Background Image
Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  7 / 46 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 7 / 46 Next Page
Page Background

Volume 5, Issue 2, Spring 2016

Infinity Journal

Page 5

Risk Distance

Geoffrey Demarest, Ivan B.Welch, and Charles K. Bartles

An economist, Professor Boulding demonstrated his thinking

with charts. As depicted in Figure 1, Professor Boulding

imagined the geographic world simplified as the limitless line

A-B, with point A being one country and point B another in a

world of only two countries.The line between points A and B

represents the distance between the two countries.

Figure 1: The Loss of Strength Gradient in a single-line world.

[iv]

Lines A-H and B-K represent each country’s amount of military

coercive power.The slope of the lines H-L,H-E,or K-M represent

the loss of effective military power as distance increases –

the loss of strength gradient. Point D (between A and B) is

derived as the geographic point in the world at which the

two countries, although unequal in overall military capacity

and capability, have equal strength. The graphic suggests

(shown by line H-H’) that country A could achieve enough

military power such that country B would have no place in

the A-B world where B would enjoy military strength equal

to that of A. However, part of Boulding’s suggestion, in an

obvious simplification of the bi-polar US-Soviet confrontation,

is also that a modest increase in coercive power on the

part of B, the Soviets, could ameliorate or overcome even a

great effort on the part of A, the United States, to increase

its total and relative coercive power. An increase in coercive

power by country B (represented by the line K-K’) might

move the geographic point of equality to point D’ and so

on logically. In his theoretical schematic, B could even move

the geographic point of equal power closer to A in spite

of A having increased its total power more than did B. With

this observation about the relationship of force-to-distance

in mind, Professor Boulding supposed that placing coercive

force forward in Europe was a more reasonable way to

favorably enhance relative US strength than an increase in

total US power would be. Even this conclusion he clothed in

disclaimers and exceptions.

In Figure 3 below, we re-make Boulding’s A-B single-line world

into a globe, but continue to consider the strict competition

of only the two countries A and B (we drop the allusion to the

Cold War, now centering the two competitors on the poles),

then the line of equal power (Circle D) makes a parallel

around the world.[v] That parallel is closer to one pole than

to the other, reflecting the greater total coercive force of A

over B. In this simplified world, the surface area wherein B

continues to enjoy greater strength appears in the shape of

a beanie or simple yarmulke.

Figure 2: The Loss of Strength Gradient in a circular world.

Depicting the points of equal power and the areas of

superiority would become quite an intellectual and artistic

chore if we were to populate our imagined, spherical world

with several countries of differing amounts of military power,

each with varying national sizes and shapes. If we were to

interpolate the idea further toward reality by including many

dozens of countries, all conspiring alliances and constantly

evolving in coercive power, the depiction would be nearly

impossible to create. Perhaps because of that impossibility,

writers on strategy who have gone about comparing

countries’ military power tend to overlook the effect of

distance entirely. They concentrate instead on direct factors

of strength such as territorial space, population, economic

performance, diplomatic acumen, technical innovation,

cyber power, cultural influence and so on.None of the entries

in a recent bibliography (prepared by the library of one of the

US national strategy colleges) on the elements of national

power discusses distance.[vi] This oblivion to the effect of

distance on power does not, however, make the influence of

distance go away.

All the above begs another question regarding the true

measure of distance itself. Distance can be categorized as:

Euclidean, cost or friction, and risk. Euclidean distance is

unimpeded ‘normal’ mathematical or geometrical distance

measured in established units such as meters or miles –

sometimes said, ‘as the crow flies’. For most purposes, we

measure

cost distances

as the time and money or other

resources necessary to move people and things from one

location to another. Risk distance, again, is the distance to

a perceived, theoretical point in time and space beyond

which it would be imprudent, irresponsible or self-destructive

to proceed in some activity. For the most part,

cost

and

risk

distances are inversely related: Increases in a cost distance

can shorten the predicted risk distance for military endeavor.

For instance,a perceived point of unacceptable risk might be

closer to home or sooner in time if extreme hot dry weather